Contact UsSearch
Click for Search Instructions
Home > Get Involved

Submission DIVINE-1593 (Online)

Submission By Michael Divine
AddressNew Westminster, BC,
Organization
Date20040823
CategoryElectoral system change
Abstract
A proposal for a majority system with provision for at large minority representation in the legislature. [6 pages]

Submission Content
AMENDED SUBMISSION TO THE CITIZENS ASSEMBLY

AN 'AV/MIXED MEMBERSHIP PROPORTIONALITY SYSTEM'
(Original submission Devine 1343 - August 13, 2004)


This is an amended version of previous submission (Divine 1343). This version expands, clarifies, and improves the original submission.Two appendices show the results of using section II of this system in the 2001 and 1996 provincial elections.

Thank you for the very important work you are doing. A fair, workable voting system is the foundation of democratic government. The many distortions in our present system deprive too many citizens of a voice in the electoral process and discourage them from voting.

Here are my objections to the present system:

1) It has given us a majority party with a grossly disproportional share of the legislature. (2001)
2) It has given us a majority party that decisively lost the popular vote. (1996)
3) Minor parties have not been represented or are have been grossly under-represented in the legislature.
4) The ideas and views of minor parties have not been debated or even given serious voice in the legislature.
5) We seem to oscillate from one arrogant majority party in power to the next arrogant majority party.
6) Under the present system, majority party lawmakers too often act as rubberstamps, mindlessly cheerleading legislation that they've barely looked at. Debate is an endless sham of empty posturing and self-congratulation. How can sound, thoughtful legislation come out of such an atmosphere?

I have looked at a number of voting systems on your site. Some of these are quite complicated. I am guided by the following principles:

1) For legitimacy, a majority or a near majority of the voters must elect MLAs in individual ridings. Elected representatives must predominate.

2) To have true debate over alternatives, minorities must be represented and heard in the legislature. The governing party requires real input from minority MLA'a with differing viewpoints if it is going to enact laws in the public interest.

3) The system must be reasonably simple, convenient, and cost effective - particularly if voters are going to accept it in the general referendum next May.

No voting system is perfect balancing and trade-offs are inevitable. The first priority is to reform the most damaging aspects of the present system. In my view, the most grievous harm is done by the first-past-the-post or plurality system when there are more than two candidates in a riding. A distinct minority candidate is often elected because another minority candidate siphons votes from a stronger candidate. This is wrong in a representative democracy. I want to support my first choice even though that choice may have little chance to win, but I don't want a poor third choice to win because I vote my conscience. I believe that the 'AV/Mixed Member Proportionality' system presented in the following sections would help to remedy this problem and the problem of minority representation. The alternative vote system outlined in section I would, by itself, be a significant improvement over FPTP, simply because it would allow the voter to freely make a first choice (even if that choice was an unelectable minor party candidate), without worrying that this would help elect an unacceptable alternative. This system would also tend to increase the visibility and vote count of minor parties while modestly increasing their representation in some cases. The proportionality system outlined in section II would, by itself, also be an improvement over the present system providing reasonably proportional outcomes in most elections. I believe that a system based on sections I and II would be a little more complicated but an improvement over both of these systems. (For all three of these systems you would need an additional rule to determine the governing party. For example: the party with the most first-choice popular votes would always have at least a one-seat plurality in the legislature and would form the government.) However, my final conclusion is that the best system would encompass all of sections I, II, and III as outlined below.

I) In all the existing ridings, a majority or near-majority vote would elect the MLAs. If there were more than two candidates, and no candidate got a majority of the total vote, all but the two top vote getters would be eliminated. The second choices of those voters whose first choices were eliminated would be distributed to the two remaining candidates to determine the winner. In this system, a voter could vote for a first-choice candidate while keeping a second-choice in reserve in case the first choice was eliminated and the voting went to a second round. In most cases, the second choices would be sufficient to determine a majority winner. I don't think it would be a good idea to go on to third choices if a majority winner was not attained in the second round. The vote counting would lose its transparency and simplicity, and the addition of third or even fourth choices to the totals determining the winner would dilute the winner's legitimacy. Most voters make a first choice with zero or one alternative in mind. I believe this reform would not only make for a legislature more in tune with actual voter preferences, both positive and negative, but would contribute to a final result that more accurately represented the percentage of the vote received by the top two parties. The final legislative seat adjustment, using at-large representation, would be made to more accurately reflect the first-choice voting percentages received by all the parties. (See section II)

II) Assume 80 elected seats and 20 at-large seats to be determined after the voting. Suppose the leading party got 38% of the first-choice vote and 36 seats (45%); the second party got 36% of the first-choice vote and 41 seats (51.25%); the third party got 12% of the first-choice vote and 2 seats (2.5%); the fourth party got 8% of the vote and one seat (1.25%); and 6% of the vote went to other parties/candidates. The distribution of seats is way out of proportion to the actual voting percentages. The first party has 18.4% more than its share, (45-38)/38; the second party has 42.4% more than its share, (51.25-36)/36; the third party has 79.2% less than its share, (2.5-12)/12; and the fourth party has 84.4% less than its share, (1.25-8)/8. These are the 'Representation Advantages' or 'R' advantages of the four parties before distribution of the 20 at-large seats. R indicates the degree of over or under-representation and is positive or negative, accordingly. The seat totals need to be more closely aligned to the percentages by distributing the 20 at-large seats as follows:

a) The threshold for a party's participation in the at-large distribution would be set at 5%.

b) The 20 at-large representatives would come from the highest-ranking first-choice vote totals among the losing candidates. (To compensate for differences in the voting pools among the districts, a highest-district-percentage system could also be used. I prefer the simplicity and transparency of absolute vote totals.) About 20 competitive ridings would have two (rarely more) representatives in the legislature. I believe it would be too complicated to have the voters pick from long slates of party candidates to determine the winners of the at-large seats. The voters would have to consider many candidates, and the only accountability would be to the party. In this system, an at-large MLA would be tied to a particular district (because that's where the votes came from), as well as the party.

c) The 20 seats would be distributed to the parties in a manner that most closely aligned the party seat totals to the proportion of the vote received without taking elected seats away from any party. Also, the party with the highest percentage of the popular vote would get at least the same number of seats as the party with the leading elected seat total.

d) As a first approximation, the 20 at-large seats are distributed as follows: the leading party gets 5 additional seats (the same as the party with the leading seat total); the second party gets no additional seats; the third party gets an additional 9 seats; and the fourth party gets the remaining 6 seats. Each party now has a distribution of legislative seats that is more closely proportional to the overall vote it received. The first party has 41 seats; the second party maintains its 41 seats; the third party has 11 seats; and the fourth party has 7 seats. Under this distribution the first party received 7.9% more than its proportional share, (41-38)/38; the second party received 13.9% more than its share, (41-36)/36; the third party received 8.3% less than its share, (11-12)/12; and the fourth party received 12.5% less than its share. This represents the closest possible alignment under the rules and comprises the final distribution of the 20 at-large seats. To be precise, the difference, D, between the highest and lowest R in all possible distributions has been minimized with D=26.4. A 40,41,11,8 distribution makes D=22.2, and a 41,40,11,8 distribution makes D=19.4, but both of these distributions violate rule c).

e) The above example illustrates the application of the following rules:

i) Compute each party's proportional share of the seats based on the first-choice voting percentages and a 100-seat legislature.

ii) Guided by the above computations, the at-large seats are distributed to approximate each party's percentage of the votes. No party loses any elected seats, and the party with the most popular votes must end up with at least as many seats as the party with the most elected seats.

iii) Compute the 'Representation Advantage', R, for each party under the distribution. R = ((% of total seats) minus (% of total vote)) / (% of total vote).

iv) The distribution is then adjusted, and each party's R value is recalculated until the difference between the highest and lowest R is minimized over all possible distributions.

f) In the above example, some might say that the first and second parties received more than their fair share at the expense of the third and fourth parties. But the only way to assure close proportionality while maintaining the system of local representation in the 80 existing ridings would be to add more at-large seats. That would result in more losing candidates, with lower vote totals, being included in the distribution and would tend to dilute the local representation and legitimacy of the legislature. It would also be more costly.

III) In the example, the two leading parties both have 41 seats less than a 51 seat majority. Which party governs? The following procedure would be applicable whenever an election failed to produce a party with a majority of the seats in the legislature:

a) Look at the second-choices of the two minor parties. Suppose the third party's second-choices were: 40% for the first party, 50% for the second party, and 10% for neither. The fourth party's second-choices were: 55% for the first party, 40% for the second party, and 5% for neither.

b) For purposes of determining the governing party, the third party's 11 seats are 'distributed' in the ratio of 40:50 to the first and second parties. That gives an additional 4.89 'seats' to the first party and 6.11 'seats' to the second party. Likewise, the fourth party's 7 seats are 'distributed' in the ratio 55:40 to the first and second parties. That gives an additional 4.05 'seats' to the first party and 2.95 'seats' to the second party. The total 'seats' for the first party is 41 + 4.89 + 4.05 = 49.94. The total 'seats' for the second party is 41 + 6.11 + 2.95 = 50.06. So the second party forms the government. The rationale for this procedure is simply that it provides a reasonably fair way to determine the governing party by 'distributing' the minor party seats according to the actual preferences of the minor party voters. No seats would actually change hands after the final distribution in section II. Thus, in a closely contested election, the second choices of the minor party voters would play a crucial role in determining the outcomes in individual ridings and in determining which of the major parties actually governed. Of course, this procedure would not make the task of governing any easier for the party that took charge, but it would give finality and fairness to the election process.

IV) The government would be formed by the majority or section III minority party for the following four years. No MLA would be permitted to switch parties during a term of office.

V) The voting system could only be changed by a provincial referendum.

SUMMARY:

1) Election by a majority or near majority in local ridings based on second-choice alternative voting.
2) Representation by a mixed system of local elections and proportional distribution.
3) Government by the majority party or a minority party with significant second-choice support.
4) Legislation enacted after real debate, negotiation, and compromise. Better laws produced.

The strengths of this system are:

1) Election by a majority or a near majority that would better reflect the negative as well as positive voter preferences in each riding. In a closely-contested election, a voter could make a 'true' first-choice for a minor party candidate without fearing that he or she would have no say in the final outcome. The parties would get better feedback as to their actual strength among the voters.

2) Representation in the legislature would be determined primarily by local elections but would be better balanced by a proportional distribution of 20 at-large seats. (20% of the total number of seats) A closely divided electorate would be represented by a closely divided legislature, not an artificially created majority.

3) The governing party would always have at least its proportional share of seats in the legislature.

4) Arrogant majority party rule would become less likely better laws in the overall public interest would become more likely. Government would be more open.

5) Minority governments would be more frequent. Laws would be passed after real negotiation, debate, and compromise among the parties. Legislators would cease being robots but would actually serve a constructive purpose in developing and considering legislation. Coalitions would likely form on particular pieces of legislation.
6) Minor parties would gain a foothold in the legislature and would have a chance to prove themselves to the voters, learn skills in government, increase their percentage of the vote, and eventually become the governing party.

7) The two leading parties would not be locked into their positions by inertia and would have to prove themselves to the voters or risk being marginalized.

8) No changes would be required in the existing ridings.

Naturally, there are questions and weaknesses in this system:

1) Is a legislature with 20% of its members 'un-elected', legitimate? Would the minor parties wield too much power - considering that the voters would elect very few of these parties' representatives?

2) Would the minor parties be too focused on one or two special issues rather than the concerns of the general public?

3) Would the vote for minor parties expand to the point of being divisive? Would the increased likelihood of minority government result in legislative gridlock? (In my opinion, it would be much better to have a few bills that were thoroughly debated and survived than many bills rammed through the legislature with no real debate.)

4) Should the threshold for participation in the at-large seat distribution be higher or lower than 5%? (A higher threshold could choke off nascent, minor parties. A lower threshold could give too much clout to numerous special-interest parties.)

5) Should the 20 at-large seats be increased or reduced? (Increasing the number would result in more un-elected/less representative MLA's (i.e., the MLA's would have received relatively fewer votes in their voting districts than other at-large MLA's) holding the balance of power on evenly-contested pieces of legislation. Decreasing the number of seats would result in less proportionality, more dominance by the leading party(ies), and less-scrutinized/less-representative legislation. The above example had a high degree of disproportionality in the initial outcome, yet the provision for 20 at-large seats led to a final result that was close to proportionality. In most elections it would be possible to get reasonably close to true proportionality with this number of at-large seats.)

6) The 20 additional seats would increase the cost of government.

Applications of this system to the 1996 and the 2001 elections, without the alternative voting outlined in sections I and III, are included in the two appendices.

APPENDIX A 2001 election results under section II of this system:

Actual results: 79 elected seats

1) Liberal: 57.6% vote 77 seats (97.5%) R= +69%
2) NDP: 21.6% vote .2 seats (2.5%) ...R= -88%
3) Green: 12.4% vote ..0 seats (0.0%) ...R= -100%
4) MP: 3.2% vote ..0 seats (0.0%) ...R= -100%
5) UP: 3.2% vote ..0 seats (0.0%) ...R= -100%
6) Other: 2.0% vote ..0 seats (0.0%) ...R= -100%

System results: 79 elected seats + 20 at-large seats (20%) = 99 seats

1) Liberal: 57.6% vote .77 seats (77.8%) R= +35.1%
2) NDP: 21.6% vote .14 seats (14.1%) R= -34.7%
3) Green: 12.4% vote . 8 seats (8.1%) ...R= -34.7%
4) MP: 3.2% vote ..0 seats (0.0%) ...R= -100%
5) UP: 3.2% vote ..0 seats (0.0%) ...R= -100%
6) Other: 2.0% vote ..0 seats (0.0%) ...R= -100%

These system results are a vast improvement over the actual results in this extremely disproportional election. The Liberals would still be over-represented and would dominate the legislature, but the second and third parties would have had much more representation. If section I alternative voting had been included, proportionality might have further improved. For example, assuming the NDP had elected an additional three representatives and the Greens had elected two representatives, the final seat totals would have been: Liberal: 72 seats (R= +26.2%), NDP: 17 seats (R= -20.3%), and Green: 10 seats (R= -18.5%)


APPENDIX B 1996 election results under section II of this system:

Actual results: 75 elected seats

1) Liberal: 42.0% vote .33 seats (44.0%) R= + 4.8%
2) NDP: 39.6% vote .39 seats (52.0%) R= +31.3%
3) BCR: 9.3% vote ..2 seats (2.7%) R= -71.0%
4) PDA: 5.8% vote ..1 seat (1.3%) R= -77.6%
5) Other: 3.3% vote ..0 seats (0.0%) R= -100%

System results: 75 elected seats + 19 at-large seats (20%) = 94 seats

1) Liberal: 42.0% vote .40 seats (42.6%) R= + 1.4%
2) NDP: 39.6% vote .39 seats (41.5%) .R= + 4.8%
3) BCR: 9.3% vote ...9 seats (9.6%) ....R= + 3.2%
4) PDA: 5.8% vote ...6 seats (6.4%) R= +10.3%
5) Other: 3.3% vote ...0 seats (0.0%) R= - 100%

These system results give a very close alignment with the actual voting percentages. All the parties are marginally over-represented at the expense of 'Other'. Note that the minimum difference rule narrowly gives an extra seat to the PDA or BCR at the expense of the Liberals. (A 40,39,9,6 distribution gives a difference of 10.3-1.4=8.9 between the highest and lowest R values; a 41,39,9,5 distribution gives a difference of 4.8-(-8.6) =13.4; and a 41,39,8,6 distribution gives a difference of 10.3-(-8.6)=18.9. Also, a 41,38,9,6 distribution would have given an even lower difference (10.3-2.0=8.3) but would have taken away an elected seat from the NDP, and a 39,40,9,6 distribution would have given a difference of 10.3-(-1.2)=11.5, but the popular vote leader's seat total would not have matched the total of the party with the leading number of elected seats.) Nevertheless, the Liberals would have formed a minority government. I can only speculate about what would have happened if sections I and III had been included in the system. With respect to section I, if alternative voting had been included, more elected seats would probably have been taken by the Liberals than the NDP, but the overall seat totals would have been nearly identical. With respect to section III, it is likely that the Liberals would have obtained the necessary 7+ seats out of the 15 seats 'distributed' from the two minor parties and would have formed the government.

© 2003 Citizens' Assembly on Electoral ReformSite powered by levelCMSSite Map | Privacy Policy